QUOTE: Originally posted by greyhounds Now once you've got the grain in a truck, does it make sense to take it to a small country elevator, then transfer it to that elevator, hold it there, then transfer it to smaller rail cars for shortline movement, then transfer it again to a larger elevator, hold it there, then transfer it to a main line shuttle train? Or do you just drive the truck to the large elevator in the first place? It will depend on the specific situation, but if I had to bet ( and I do bet on things ), I'd bet that it will be generally more efficient to just drive the truck to the large elevator.
QUOTE: Originally posted by greyhounds Yes, but. The grain isn't originating at a country elevator. It's originating in a farm field. I remember watching a Wisconsin farmer harvest his corn. It was dark and the John Deere combine just went back and forth, it's headlights showing the way through the corn field. The hopper on the combine would get full, then he'd ( or she'd, I don't know which gender was driving) unload into a semi in the field. Semi's can go into farm fields where the freight originates. Trains can't. When the semi got full, it drove off. Now once you've got the grain in a truck, does it make sense to take it to a small country elevator, then transfer it to that elevator, hold it there, then transfer it to smaller rail cars for shortline movement, then transfer it again to a larger elevator, hold it there, then transfer it to a main line shuttle train? Or do you just drive the truck to the large elevator in the first place? It will depend on the specific situation, but if I had to bet ( and I do bet on things ), I'd bet that it will be generally more efficient to just drive the truck to the large elevator.
QUOTE: Originally posted by greyhounds[That's like the combine and the trucks. The farmer has to "balance his/her line". He/she has to coordinate the trucks with the combine. If the farmer has to truck his grain farther to the elevator so be it. The farmer needs to hire more trucks. There is no reason that a 105K truck can't go into a field. It's a matter of ground pressure, and that can be solved by putting more axles under the truck.
QUOTE: Originally posted by daveklepper How much business does BNSF want? Maybe they have decided that getting all the business, and it is seasonal, means capacity constraints and inability to provide the service their year-round customers expect. So they are deliberately loosing the seasonal business to insure keeping the year-round business. Does this make sense?
QUOTE: Originally posted by PNWRMNM Michael, Are you quoting revenue per car or revenue per unit? BNSF's web site talks in units, not cars. My take on this is a unit is a car or a trailer or a container. If so, revuenue per trailer/container should be at least doubled to get per car equavalent. Consumer goods is where the intermodal business resides in BNSF's structure, so one would expect low revenue per unit there. In short, I think you may be comparing apples to oranges. Mac
QUOTE: Originally posted by MichaelSol Well Dave, that is certainly an interesting way to look at it. From an expense standpoint, it seems that the railroads have taken an odd view. Grain transportation is already such a streamlined operation compared to industrial or consumer traffic. No congested yards to deal with, no vandalism losses, all the traffic is out in the middle of nowhwere, where the crews stop, get the job done, and move on. Exactly what "costs" these companies are trying to "wring" out of the process is not entirely clear to me. Matt Rose does say the following: "For several years we've improved our efficiency with longer trains for coal, grain, and other commodities." Thirty years ago, I sat down with some Milwaukee people who were forward looking, with the idea of trying to envision the most "efficient" rail operation. This was before modelling was a sophisticated art/science. After a few months of chewing it over, we concluded that shorter, faster trains were more profitable than longer, slower trains. The alleged savings in crew costs with longer trains were cancelled out entirely by the increased costs of getting the train from point A to point B, and, at some point in the congestion matrix, crew productivity in the scenario with longer trains began to fall quite dramatically. The longer the trains, at a certain level of business, the more inefficient the railroad became. The point was, the longer that the trains were on the track, the less efficient the railroad became and the more expensive was overall train operation. So, BNSF proudly announces that its idea of efficiency is longer trains, on lines that are already pretty congested. Interestingly, as the Internet became more clearly understood in terms of routing efficiency, the idea was exactly the opposite, break messages and information flow into small and discrete units, send them off, and the assemble them at their destination. Networks are more efficient with small units, rather than large units . Railroads have developed the idea, that is contrary to both models and experience in other industries, that large units are most efficient to move over crowded networks. And even though its own customers don't like it, and it costs the customers more money, BNSF seems bound and deterrmined to force its customers into this idea of "efficiency." Is there any "efficiency"? BNSF grain trains are already among the slowest on the system at an average speed of 23.1 mph. A BNSF grain train of 15,000 tons is not an example of efficiency, rather, it is a slow moving bottleneck. Even though, by industry standards, BNSF is a pretty good mover of grain trains. However, its worst yard for dwell time is Pasco, with an average of 15.9 hours. Not to pick on BNSF, UP is just awful, with yard dwell times of 20-30 hours. But, Pasco happens to be where some of the longest grain trains are routed. Now, what is the breakeven on trains.? The average carload on the BNSF earns $1074. It travels 1045 miles. To breakeven, that carload would earn $924.00 on the same haul. That is, the average carload generates a profit of $150. What does BNSF earn from a carload of grain on that same line-haul? Well, Brockton, Montana is 1064 miles from Portland. A carload of wheat brings revenue to the BNSF of $3,938.00. Now, admittedly, Brockton is located in Montana and suffers from that uniquely BNSF policy that, if you ship in Montana, you will pay a lot more. The system average for 1064 miles, shipping grain, is only $2699 per carload. Either way, that is enormously profitable Compared to the BNSF average, Montana wheat is nearly 25 times as profitable per carload as BNSF earns from its typical business. Compare that to the BNSF Consumer Group which represents 40% of BNSF revenue. The average CG carload brings a yield of $874. Compared to grain, which has no real "handling" needs -- it doesn't break, it doesn't dent -- CG is a high cost operation, serving the most congested yards on the most congested routes. The CG group loses about $50 per carload carried. The average carload of grain on the BNSF system brings $1969. This compares not only with CG at $874, but with Industrial at $1568/carload, and Coal at $1028 per carload. Wheat is the most profitable item carried on the BNSF, and is likely the least costly to the Company in terms of associated operating expenses. Yet, Matt Rose says nothing about improving "efficiency" for the CG group, but only talks about coal, grain and "other commodities." But, as the numbers, and maybe even some common sense should show, "they ain't the problem." The fact is, based on profitability, BNSF should be turning sommersaults to keep those grain customers happy, and carrying as much wheat as possible, rather than losing the business entirely, as its policies have been doing. What is interesting is that the Company is offering a 12% cut in its own revenue on this profitable commodity. To make longer, most likely less efficient trains which exacerbate congestion delays on the system, increasing operating expenses overall. Naturally, someone would see it as mismanagement to make an extraordinarily good profit, because it might lead to congestion, but good business practice to carry 40% of the company traffic at a loss, even though that accounts for all of the congestion, and not do anything about it. Why on earth would a "year round customer" that loses money be so important to keep, compared to a customer that, in the season, generates a profit of 200-300%? Further, and perhaps more significantly, there is not a particular seasonality in grain shipping. Misunderstanding the difference between grain marketing and grain growing is fairly typical. In 2004, for instance, to Pacific Northwest Ports, the quarterly carloads arriving during the week of 12/31/03 were 3500, 3/24/04 -- 5200, 6/15/04 -- 4800, 9/8/04 -- 3000, 12/01/04 -- 5000, carloads. As you will note, the smallest number of carloads was during "the season" of harvest. Grain shipping is, in fact, a year round business. However, it is thinking like this, and Instances like this, that go a long way to explaining why this Company cannot earn its own cost of capital. Best regards, Michael Sol
QUOTE: Lower revenues AND angry customers. How much more "efficiency" like this can a railroad handle?
QUOTE: Originally posted by Chris30 QUOTE: Lower revenues AND angry customers. How much more "efficiency" like this can a railroad handle? I mentioned it before in this thread... revenue gained from serving small elevators on deteriorating branches would have to be spent on maintenance at some point to keep the business and support the heavier cars that most deteriorating midwest grain branches can no longer support. Lower revenues? What $$. Besides, the big railroads are already stretched thin on grain car supply. They're not going to upset their biggest customers to serve the little elevator that could. It's all about $$ and car cycle times.
QUOTE: "Lower revenues?? What $$."
QUOTE: 5. Average system carload revenue, as you stated, for 1064 miles of ag products was $2699 per carload. How did you determine that number? 6. What are the cycle times for the grain shuttle trains? You indicated cycle times increased from 24 to 26 days, was this for all system cars, or just grain cars, or grain shuttle cars?
QUOTE: Originally posted by MichaelSol That's the irony of this: it costs the customer more in increased transportation costs to the shuttle elevators, and increased costs to build and operate shuttle elevators, and the railroad receives less revenue. This is one bright idea. Nobody wins. I'll disagree with you on that last point. Clearly the trucking companies win, and do so at the expense of both the grain marketers and the railroads. Yet another inadvertent gift from the railroads to the so-called "enemy" aka truckers. Rather, longer, slower trains appear to result in increased system congestion, do result in increased track maintenance expenses, and do result in longer terminal dwell times as a system effect that "suggests" that increased efficiency is not the result, but rather statistically measurable inefficiency is apparently the result. That all trains are affected by the increased congestion resulting from bigger, longer, slower grain trains. It would appear that this bent toward clogging the tracks with ostensible "efficiency" consists is a disease that is systemic, hard-wired into the railroad management culture. If this idea of product consolidation onto as many cars as will fit onto a siding was developed from an economic model, it is easy to see that it was a model developed with limited variable analysis. Such is the heart and soul of the Staggers Act, on the surface a "no-brainer" while in its long term impacts a "no-brainer" of a different sort. Staggers only partially "deregulated" the railroads, providing independent rate setting and price contracting, but doing nothing to effect head to head rail competition for all rail shippers. The latter is crucially necessary to ensure innovation, the only way to keep the entire industry from homogenizing into a star-crossed bandwagon of eventual economic failure. Some of you have explicitly or implicitly infered that competition is bad for the rail industry, because if railroads are forced to compete for each and every potential customer they will not be able to achieve revenue adaquacy. This is simply circular reasoning, because without competitve incentives the customer base will be put off (via capacity reductions, service consolidations, service delays, service refusals, et al), and without an ever increasing customer base a company, any company, not just railroads will not be able to achieve revenue adaquacy. How many more examples of railroad management underachievement will this nation have to put up with before you all will concede that Staggers is ultimately a failure? It's not that deregulation is not a desirable application of government oversight, it's that partial deregulation is sometimes worse than no deregulation at all. Staggers is partial deregulation, evidenced by the railroads' balance sheets, and evidenced by the tremendous loss of railroad employment/trackage/market share over the last two decades. If we want to do this thing right, then we need to fully deregulate the industry into a competitive venture that pleases both the investors and the customers. You all know my idea for full deregulation (it goes by the initials "o" and "a"), but I am willing to consider any else's ideas for implementing full deregulation in the broadest sense of the word. If anyone has an idea for bringing back the rail saturation of the 1970's, wherein all but a few areas of the country had true head to head rail competition in the form of the private closed access system, then let's hear it. Reply Edit bobwilcox Member sinceDecember 2001 From: Crozet, VA 1,049 posts Posted by bobwilcox on Thursday, June 30, 2005 9:25 PM QUOTE: Originally posted by MichaelSol I do not find the benefits anywhere in the financial statements, and never have. I do not think you will. The public documents are for investors not the railroads maketing department. They are supposed to tell the investors how the business is doing. This was one of several flaws in the old ICC Form A accounting system. It took financial data and crammed it into a cost model. A system designed to tell stockholders if Jay Gould was cheating them again just does help say what it cost to move a car from Podunck to E. Budda, TX. The traffic costing systems are competly different animals. The margins on traffic are built up from specific revenue data (ie. waybills)and specific operating costs. These measurement systems are vastly better since the old days of needing to use system wide averages for important cost components. As an examle, on the CNW thirty years ago we plugged in a system wide annual average for track maintance[:)] cost ($/MGTM). Thirty years later these types of costs are keeped at the crew distirct level. Today you we see vast cost differences for a car travelling from Houston to a S. IL Gateway vs. a car wandering up a branch in the PNW. Also, you use history better than just an annual number. Bob Reply MP173 Member sinceMay 2004 From: Valparaiso, In 5,921 posts Posted by MP173 on Thursday, June 30, 2005 9:31 PM Without Staggers, this country's rail system would have been a MESS. Dont know about you, but I remember the 70's quite well, and not only was it not pretty, but it was financially ugly. The question still remains, how will you provide open access? I am certainly not happy with the recent Supreme Court ruling on the ability to condemn and seize private property. I believe we will be well on the road to socialism in this country if this trend continues. What is next? Government siezure of all railroads and then parcelling out routes? I have extreme moral issues with our government taking anything from private citizens or companies. Besides, how would they pay for the property they would seize? ed Reply Anonymous Member sinceApril 2003 305,205 posts Posted by Anonymous on Thursday, June 30, 2005 10:22 PM Just a couple of weeks ago in Rochelle I heard that the Burly-Q would be offering local farmers a dime per bushel of corn extra if they got their product to the BNSF's own granaries instead of patronizing the local elevators (those that couldn't scrape up seventy-five or more carloads, one supposes). Wha'd'y'all think of this? Reply Edit arbfbe Member sinceFebruary 2002 910 posts Posted by arbfbe on Thursday, June 30, 2005 10:31 PM Railroad effeciency in an accounting sense had two final components. Train miles, representing costs and ton miles representing revenues. Combined they represent a figure of train ton miles. So if you decrease costs by reducing train miles, i.e. run fewer trains and increase revenues, i.e. increase car loads there is only one conclusion to the accounting model. You run the fewest, heaviest trains you can move over the system. Fatter, fewer trains becomes it's own goal. I suppose managers are rewarded for it and the underlings in the yards and dispatch offices take the heat for not keeping these trains fluid despite the fact they are too long to arrive or be made up in the yards, they are too long for many sidings and so have to wait at or move to the sidings that are long enough, cascading delays to all other trains and they eat up expensive locomotives like cheap candy, except locomotives are not cheap. They also sit in yards plugging tracks until they reach the optimal tonnage decreed by managers who want to see the most effeciency based on their accounting model. Car cycle times increase and yard switching decreases account there is no free space to use to sort cars. So until the accounting measures change it will be the same old, same old. Alan Reply MichaelSol Member sinceOctober 2004 3,190 posts Posted by MichaelSol on Thursday, June 30, 2005 11:07 PM QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 In comparing grain vs other commodities, it sure appears the grain rates are much higher.... Something about the transporting of grain by rail results in higher transportation costs than other commodities.....why would that be? Perhaps the answer to that lends itself to the reasons behind this entire debate. Concluding that because the rates received are higher, therefore this shows that costs must be higher is quite a leap. I see no evidence whatsover from a detailed analysis of the tariff system that the BNSF tariff model is cost based but rather, is market based. Indeed, that's the problem, it is not cost-based, and in fact can work in such a fashion that, through the influence of cycle times, it costs the Company money, rather than contributes revenue to it. I sincerely doubt, in those instances, that BNSF negotiates a higher tariff than the one it publishes. Best regards, Michael Sol Reply Anonymous Member sinceApril 2003 305,205 posts Posted by Anonymous on Thursday, June 30, 2005 11:47 PM QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 Without Staggers, this country's rail system would have been a MESS. Dont know about you, but I remember the 70's quite well, and not only was it not pretty, but it was financially ugly. The question still remains, how will you provide open access? ed This country's rail system is still a mess, albeit a much retrenched one. Look at how much has been lost in railroad employment, relative market share (especially in terms of $$ share), customer access to rail lines, railroad responsiveness to customer demands, etc. There's enough evidence that railroading was in far better shape pre-Staggers than post-Staggers if you use these benchmarks. Indeed, if it wasn't for PRB coal and free trade policies (which have given new life to COFC) you can almost make a case that Staggers has accellerated the decline of railroading in this country, perhaps by allowing monopolistic management to hang themselves with their own rope, a rope that exists soley due to lack of head to head competition. The point I am trying to make is that neither the pre-Staggers era of comprehensive regulation, nor the post-Staggers era of comprehensive retrenchment, is doing much to guarantee that railroading will finally achieve it's promise. The only way to guarantee railroading's long term prosperity is to (1)make sure all rail customers have access to competitive rail rates and services (which will dramatically increase market share on the demand side), and (2) equalize the cost of constructing and maintaining the rail infrastructure with the cost allocation associated with constructing and maintaining highways, waterways, and airports, so that we may finally see if indeed railroads would assume a 70% natural market share. My views on how to achieve this are well known on this forum: Separate the current Class I oligarchy into infrastructure companies and transporter companies, regulate the infrastructure companies as public utilities while providing public track construction via a share of the federal fuel tax (which would be paid by all transportation modes and then reallocated to better reflect intermodal realities) and maintenance support in the form of maintenance tax credits (plus a property tax exemption, recognizing open access rail lines as public right of way by proxy), and then let the rail transporters go at it in a relatively unregulated environment, similar to trucking transporters. Market forces that have been absent since the beginning of the railroad era would finally be unleashed. Some transporters would fail, while others would prosper, and outsiders would finally be able to test their own theories of rail service innovations. The bottom line is this: If BNSF doesn't want to provide carload or small carset service offerings, then let someone else fill that void. Right now that void is being partially filled by truckers as best as the free market allows, but with predictable long term driver shortages resulting (due to the inherent inability of the trucking genre to handle large volume commodity movements on a consistent efficient basis), it is probably the consensus on this forum that some form of rail transport would be much better at filling that void, and it is a consensus that is well founded. But this can only occur if the proprietary closed acces system is opened up to competitors, or if we can somehow return to the days of multiple railroad company tracks laid into each customer's facility. Even the most ardent anti-open access opponents would probably prefer this scenario to that of pre-Stagger's regulation. Reply Edit bobwilcox Member sinceDecember 2001 From: Crozet, VA 1,049 posts Posted by bobwilcox on Friday, July 1, 2005 6:09 AM QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 Something about the transporting of grain by rail results in higher transportation costs than other commodities.....why would that be? Perhaps the answer to that lends itself to the reasons behind this entire debate. I can not think of any Class I that makes rates from the veiwpoint of costs. The only businesses that can do this are those working under emergency conditions with the government(ie cost plus)or public utilities such electric distribution. During the last 25 years railroad's have priced based on the demand for their service. I have seen significant rail commodities moving on the same railroad with one lane at a 10% markeup and the next lane at 200+% markup. If you took a look at a North American Class I's margins by major commodities (ie greater than $1 million per year) you would see margins from 5% to 250%. Bob Reply 123456 Join our Community! Our community is FREE to join. To participate you must either login or register for an account. Login » Register » Search the Community Newsletter Sign-Up By signing up you may also receive occasional reader surveys and special offers from Trains magazine.Please view our privacy policy More great sites from Kalmbach Media Terms Of Use | Privacy Policy | Copyright Policy
I'll disagree with you on that last point. Clearly the trucking companies win, and do so at the expense of both the grain marketers and the railroads. Yet another inadvertent gift from the railroads to the so-called "enemy" aka truckers. Rather, longer, slower trains appear to result in increased system congestion, do result in increased track maintenance expenses, and do result in longer terminal dwell times as a system effect that "suggests" that increased efficiency is not the result, but rather statistically measurable inefficiency is apparently the result. That all trains are affected by the increased congestion resulting from bigger, longer, slower grain trains. It would appear that this bent toward clogging the tracks with ostensible "efficiency" consists is a disease that is systemic, hard-wired into the railroad management culture. If this idea of product consolidation onto as many cars as will fit onto a siding was developed from an economic model, it is easy to see that it was a model developed with limited variable analysis. Such is the heart and soul of the Staggers Act, on the surface a "no-brainer" while in its long term impacts a "no-brainer" of a different sort. Staggers only partially "deregulated" the railroads, providing independent rate setting and price contracting, but doing nothing to effect head to head rail competition for all rail shippers. The latter is crucially necessary to ensure innovation, the only way to keep the entire industry from homogenizing into a star-crossed bandwagon of eventual economic failure. Some of you have explicitly or implicitly infered that competition is bad for the rail industry, because if railroads are forced to compete for each and every potential customer they will not be able to achieve revenue adaquacy. This is simply circular reasoning, because without competitve incentives the customer base will be put off (via capacity reductions, service consolidations, service delays, service refusals, et al), and without an ever increasing customer base a company, any company, not just railroads will not be able to achieve revenue adaquacy. How many more examples of railroad management underachievement will this nation have to put up with before you all will concede that Staggers is ultimately a failure? It's not that deregulation is not a desirable application of government oversight, it's that partial deregulation is sometimes worse than no deregulation at all. Staggers is partial deregulation, evidenced by the railroads' balance sheets, and evidenced by the tremendous loss of railroad employment/trackage/market share over the last two decades. If we want to do this thing right, then we need to fully deregulate the industry into a competitive venture that pleases both the investors and the customers. You all know my idea for full deregulation (it goes by the initials "o" and "a"), but I am willing to consider any else's ideas for implementing full deregulation in the broadest sense of the word. If anyone has an idea for bringing back the rail saturation of the 1970's, wherein all but a few areas of the country had true head to head rail competition in the form of the private closed access system, then let's hear it. Reply Edit bobwilcox Member sinceDecember 2001 From: Crozet, VA 1,049 posts Posted by bobwilcox on Thursday, June 30, 2005 9:25 PM QUOTE: Originally posted by MichaelSol I do not find the benefits anywhere in the financial statements, and never have. I do not think you will. The public documents are for investors not the railroads maketing department. They are supposed to tell the investors how the business is doing. This was one of several flaws in the old ICC Form A accounting system. It took financial data and crammed it into a cost model. A system designed to tell stockholders if Jay Gould was cheating them again just does help say what it cost to move a car from Podunck to E. Budda, TX. The traffic costing systems are competly different animals. The margins on traffic are built up from specific revenue data (ie. waybills)and specific operating costs. These measurement systems are vastly better since the old days of needing to use system wide averages for important cost components. As an examle, on the CNW thirty years ago we plugged in a system wide annual average for track maintance[:)] cost ($/MGTM). Thirty years later these types of costs are keeped at the crew distirct level. Today you we see vast cost differences for a car travelling from Houston to a S. IL Gateway vs. a car wandering up a branch in the PNW. Also, you use history better than just an annual number. Bob Reply MP173 Member sinceMay 2004 From: Valparaiso, In 5,921 posts Posted by MP173 on Thursday, June 30, 2005 9:31 PM Without Staggers, this country's rail system would have been a MESS. Dont know about you, but I remember the 70's quite well, and not only was it not pretty, but it was financially ugly. The question still remains, how will you provide open access? I am certainly not happy with the recent Supreme Court ruling on the ability to condemn and seize private property. I believe we will be well on the road to socialism in this country if this trend continues. What is next? Government siezure of all railroads and then parcelling out routes? I have extreme moral issues with our government taking anything from private citizens or companies. Besides, how would they pay for the property they would seize? ed Reply Anonymous Member sinceApril 2003 305,205 posts Posted by Anonymous on Thursday, June 30, 2005 10:22 PM Just a couple of weeks ago in Rochelle I heard that the Burly-Q would be offering local farmers a dime per bushel of corn extra if they got their product to the BNSF's own granaries instead of patronizing the local elevators (those that couldn't scrape up seventy-five or more carloads, one supposes). Wha'd'y'all think of this? Reply Edit arbfbe Member sinceFebruary 2002 910 posts Posted by arbfbe on Thursday, June 30, 2005 10:31 PM Railroad effeciency in an accounting sense had two final components. Train miles, representing costs and ton miles representing revenues. Combined they represent a figure of train ton miles. So if you decrease costs by reducing train miles, i.e. run fewer trains and increase revenues, i.e. increase car loads there is only one conclusion to the accounting model. You run the fewest, heaviest trains you can move over the system. Fatter, fewer trains becomes it's own goal. I suppose managers are rewarded for it and the underlings in the yards and dispatch offices take the heat for not keeping these trains fluid despite the fact they are too long to arrive or be made up in the yards, they are too long for many sidings and so have to wait at or move to the sidings that are long enough, cascading delays to all other trains and they eat up expensive locomotives like cheap candy, except locomotives are not cheap. They also sit in yards plugging tracks until they reach the optimal tonnage decreed by managers who want to see the most effeciency based on their accounting model. Car cycle times increase and yard switching decreases account there is no free space to use to sort cars. So until the accounting measures change it will be the same old, same old. Alan Reply MichaelSol Member sinceOctober 2004 3,190 posts Posted by MichaelSol on Thursday, June 30, 2005 11:07 PM QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 In comparing grain vs other commodities, it sure appears the grain rates are much higher.... Something about the transporting of grain by rail results in higher transportation costs than other commodities.....why would that be? Perhaps the answer to that lends itself to the reasons behind this entire debate. Concluding that because the rates received are higher, therefore this shows that costs must be higher is quite a leap. I see no evidence whatsover from a detailed analysis of the tariff system that the BNSF tariff model is cost based but rather, is market based. Indeed, that's the problem, it is not cost-based, and in fact can work in such a fashion that, through the influence of cycle times, it costs the Company money, rather than contributes revenue to it. I sincerely doubt, in those instances, that BNSF negotiates a higher tariff than the one it publishes. Best regards, Michael Sol Reply Anonymous Member sinceApril 2003 305,205 posts Posted by Anonymous on Thursday, June 30, 2005 11:47 PM QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 Without Staggers, this country's rail system would have been a MESS. Dont know about you, but I remember the 70's quite well, and not only was it not pretty, but it was financially ugly. The question still remains, how will you provide open access? ed This country's rail system is still a mess, albeit a much retrenched one. Look at how much has been lost in railroad employment, relative market share (especially in terms of $$ share), customer access to rail lines, railroad responsiveness to customer demands, etc. There's enough evidence that railroading was in far better shape pre-Staggers than post-Staggers if you use these benchmarks. Indeed, if it wasn't for PRB coal and free trade policies (which have given new life to COFC) you can almost make a case that Staggers has accellerated the decline of railroading in this country, perhaps by allowing monopolistic management to hang themselves with their own rope, a rope that exists soley due to lack of head to head competition. The point I am trying to make is that neither the pre-Staggers era of comprehensive regulation, nor the post-Staggers era of comprehensive retrenchment, is doing much to guarantee that railroading will finally achieve it's promise. The only way to guarantee railroading's long term prosperity is to (1)make sure all rail customers have access to competitive rail rates and services (which will dramatically increase market share on the demand side), and (2) equalize the cost of constructing and maintaining the rail infrastructure with the cost allocation associated with constructing and maintaining highways, waterways, and airports, so that we may finally see if indeed railroads would assume a 70% natural market share. My views on how to achieve this are well known on this forum: Separate the current Class I oligarchy into infrastructure companies and transporter companies, regulate the infrastructure companies as public utilities while providing public track construction via a share of the federal fuel tax (which would be paid by all transportation modes and then reallocated to better reflect intermodal realities) and maintenance support in the form of maintenance tax credits (plus a property tax exemption, recognizing open access rail lines as public right of way by proxy), and then let the rail transporters go at it in a relatively unregulated environment, similar to trucking transporters. Market forces that have been absent since the beginning of the railroad era would finally be unleashed. Some transporters would fail, while others would prosper, and outsiders would finally be able to test their own theories of rail service innovations. The bottom line is this: If BNSF doesn't want to provide carload or small carset service offerings, then let someone else fill that void. Right now that void is being partially filled by truckers as best as the free market allows, but with predictable long term driver shortages resulting (due to the inherent inability of the trucking genre to handle large volume commodity movements on a consistent efficient basis), it is probably the consensus on this forum that some form of rail transport would be much better at filling that void, and it is a consensus that is well founded. But this can only occur if the proprietary closed acces system is opened up to competitors, or if we can somehow return to the days of multiple railroad company tracks laid into each customer's facility. Even the most ardent anti-open access opponents would probably prefer this scenario to that of pre-Stagger's regulation. Reply Edit bobwilcox Member sinceDecember 2001 From: Crozet, VA 1,049 posts Posted by bobwilcox on Friday, July 1, 2005 6:09 AM QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 Something about the transporting of grain by rail results in higher transportation costs than other commodities.....why would that be? Perhaps the answer to that lends itself to the reasons behind this entire debate. I can not think of any Class I that makes rates from the veiwpoint of costs. The only businesses that can do this are those working under emergency conditions with the government(ie cost plus)or public utilities such electric distribution. During the last 25 years railroad's have priced based on the demand for their service. I have seen significant rail commodities moving on the same railroad with one lane at a 10% markeup and the next lane at 200+% markup. If you took a look at a North American Class I's margins by major commodities (ie greater than $1 million per year) you would see margins from 5% to 250%. Bob Reply 123456 Join our Community! Our community is FREE to join. To participate you must either login or register for an account. Login » Register » Search the Community Newsletter Sign-Up By signing up you may also receive occasional reader surveys and special offers from Trains magazine.Please view our privacy policy More great sites from Kalmbach Media Terms Of Use | Privacy Policy | Copyright Policy
Rather, longer, slower trains appear to result in increased system congestion, do result in increased track maintenance expenses, and do result in longer terminal dwell times as a system effect that "suggests" that increased efficiency is not the result, but rather statistically measurable inefficiency is apparently the result. That all trains are affected by the increased congestion resulting from bigger, longer, slower grain trains.
QUOTE: Originally posted by MichaelSol I do not find the benefits anywhere in the financial statements, and never have. I do not think you will. The public documents are for investors not the railroads maketing department. They are supposed to tell the investors how the business is doing. This was one of several flaws in the old ICC Form A accounting system. It took financial data and crammed it into a cost model. A system designed to tell stockholders if Jay Gould was cheating them again just does help say what it cost to move a car from Podunck to E. Budda, TX. The traffic costing systems are competly different animals. The margins on traffic are built up from specific revenue data (ie. waybills)and specific operating costs. These measurement systems are vastly better since the old days of needing to use system wide averages for important cost components. As an examle, on the CNW thirty years ago we plugged in a system wide annual average for track maintance[:)] cost ($/MGTM). Thirty years later these types of costs are keeped at the crew distirct level. Today you we see vast cost differences for a car travelling from Houston to a S. IL Gateway vs. a car wandering up a branch in the PNW. Also, you use history better than just an annual number. Bob Reply MP173 Member sinceMay 2004 From: Valparaiso, In 5,921 posts Posted by MP173 on Thursday, June 30, 2005 9:31 PM Without Staggers, this country's rail system would have been a MESS. Dont know about you, but I remember the 70's quite well, and not only was it not pretty, but it was financially ugly. The question still remains, how will you provide open access? I am certainly not happy with the recent Supreme Court ruling on the ability to condemn and seize private property. I believe we will be well on the road to socialism in this country if this trend continues. What is next? Government siezure of all railroads and then parcelling out routes? I have extreme moral issues with our government taking anything from private citizens or companies. Besides, how would they pay for the property they would seize? ed Reply Anonymous Member sinceApril 2003 305,205 posts Posted by Anonymous on Thursday, June 30, 2005 10:22 PM Just a couple of weeks ago in Rochelle I heard that the Burly-Q would be offering local farmers a dime per bushel of corn extra if they got their product to the BNSF's own granaries instead of patronizing the local elevators (those that couldn't scrape up seventy-five or more carloads, one supposes). Wha'd'y'all think of this? Reply Edit arbfbe Member sinceFebruary 2002 910 posts Posted by arbfbe on Thursday, June 30, 2005 10:31 PM Railroad effeciency in an accounting sense had two final components. Train miles, representing costs and ton miles representing revenues. Combined they represent a figure of train ton miles. So if you decrease costs by reducing train miles, i.e. run fewer trains and increase revenues, i.e. increase car loads there is only one conclusion to the accounting model. You run the fewest, heaviest trains you can move over the system. Fatter, fewer trains becomes it's own goal. I suppose managers are rewarded for it and the underlings in the yards and dispatch offices take the heat for not keeping these trains fluid despite the fact they are too long to arrive or be made up in the yards, they are too long for many sidings and so have to wait at or move to the sidings that are long enough, cascading delays to all other trains and they eat up expensive locomotives like cheap candy, except locomotives are not cheap. They also sit in yards plugging tracks until they reach the optimal tonnage decreed by managers who want to see the most effeciency based on their accounting model. Car cycle times increase and yard switching decreases account there is no free space to use to sort cars. So until the accounting measures change it will be the same old, same old. Alan Reply MichaelSol Member sinceOctober 2004 3,190 posts Posted by MichaelSol on Thursday, June 30, 2005 11:07 PM QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 In comparing grain vs other commodities, it sure appears the grain rates are much higher.... Something about the transporting of grain by rail results in higher transportation costs than other commodities.....why would that be? Perhaps the answer to that lends itself to the reasons behind this entire debate. Concluding that because the rates received are higher, therefore this shows that costs must be higher is quite a leap. I see no evidence whatsover from a detailed analysis of the tariff system that the BNSF tariff model is cost based but rather, is market based. Indeed, that's the problem, it is not cost-based, and in fact can work in such a fashion that, through the influence of cycle times, it costs the Company money, rather than contributes revenue to it. I sincerely doubt, in those instances, that BNSF negotiates a higher tariff than the one it publishes. Best regards, Michael Sol Reply Anonymous Member sinceApril 2003 305,205 posts Posted by Anonymous on Thursday, June 30, 2005 11:47 PM QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 Without Staggers, this country's rail system would have been a MESS. Dont know about you, but I remember the 70's quite well, and not only was it not pretty, but it was financially ugly. The question still remains, how will you provide open access? ed This country's rail system is still a mess, albeit a much retrenched one. Look at how much has been lost in railroad employment, relative market share (especially in terms of $$ share), customer access to rail lines, railroad responsiveness to customer demands, etc. There's enough evidence that railroading was in far better shape pre-Staggers than post-Staggers if you use these benchmarks. Indeed, if it wasn't for PRB coal and free trade policies (which have given new life to COFC) you can almost make a case that Staggers has accellerated the decline of railroading in this country, perhaps by allowing monopolistic management to hang themselves with their own rope, a rope that exists soley due to lack of head to head competition. The point I am trying to make is that neither the pre-Staggers era of comprehensive regulation, nor the post-Staggers era of comprehensive retrenchment, is doing much to guarantee that railroading will finally achieve it's promise. The only way to guarantee railroading's long term prosperity is to (1)make sure all rail customers have access to competitive rail rates and services (which will dramatically increase market share on the demand side), and (2) equalize the cost of constructing and maintaining the rail infrastructure with the cost allocation associated with constructing and maintaining highways, waterways, and airports, so that we may finally see if indeed railroads would assume a 70% natural market share. My views on how to achieve this are well known on this forum: Separate the current Class I oligarchy into infrastructure companies and transporter companies, regulate the infrastructure companies as public utilities while providing public track construction via a share of the federal fuel tax (which would be paid by all transportation modes and then reallocated to better reflect intermodal realities) and maintenance support in the form of maintenance tax credits (plus a property tax exemption, recognizing open access rail lines as public right of way by proxy), and then let the rail transporters go at it in a relatively unregulated environment, similar to trucking transporters. Market forces that have been absent since the beginning of the railroad era would finally be unleashed. Some transporters would fail, while others would prosper, and outsiders would finally be able to test their own theories of rail service innovations. The bottom line is this: If BNSF doesn't want to provide carload or small carset service offerings, then let someone else fill that void. Right now that void is being partially filled by truckers as best as the free market allows, but with predictable long term driver shortages resulting (due to the inherent inability of the trucking genre to handle large volume commodity movements on a consistent efficient basis), it is probably the consensus on this forum that some form of rail transport would be much better at filling that void, and it is a consensus that is well founded. But this can only occur if the proprietary closed acces system is opened up to competitors, or if we can somehow return to the days of multiple railroad company tracks laid into each customer's facility. Even the most ardent anti-open access opponents would probably prefer this scenario to that of pre-Stagger's regulation. Reply Edit bobwilcox Member sinceDecember 2001 From: Crozet, VA 1,049 posts Posted by bobwilcox on Friday, July 1, 2005 6:09 AM QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 Something about the transporting of grain by rail results in higher transportation costs than other commodities.....why would that be? Perhaps the answer to that lends itself to the reasons behind this entire debate. I can not think of any Class I that makes rates from the veiwpoint of costs. The only businesses that can do this are those working under emergency conditions with the government(ie cost plus)or public utilities such electric distribution. During the last 25 years railroad's have priced based on the demand for their service. I have seen significant rail commodities moving on the same railroad with one lane at a 10% markeup and the next lane at 200+% markup. If you took a look at a North American Class I's margins by major commodities (ie greater than $1 million per year) you would see margins from 5% to 250%. Bob Reply 123456 Join our Community! Our community is FREE to join. To participate you must either login or register for an account. Login » Register » Search the Community Newsletter Sign-Up By signing up you may also receive occasional reader surveys and special offers from Trains magazine.Please view our privacy policy More great sites from Kalmbach Media Terms Of Use | Privacy Policy | Copyright Policy
I do not find the benefits anywhere in the financial statements, and never have.
QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 In comparing grain vs other commodities, it sure appears the grain rates are much higher.... Something about the transporting of grain by rail results in higher transportation costs than other commodities.....why would that be? Perhaps the answer to that lends itself to the reasons behind this entire debate.
QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 Without Staggers, this country's rail system would have been a MESS. Dont know about you, but I remember the 70's quite well, and not only was it not pretty, but it was financially ugly. The question still remains, how will you provide open access? ed
QUOTE: Originally posted by MP173 Something about the transporting of grain by rail results in higher transportation costs than other commodities.....why would that be? Perhaps the answer to that lends itself to the reasons behind this entire debate.
Our community is FREE to join. To participate you must either login or register for an account.