Trains.com

"Open Access" and regulation of railroad freight rates.

18453 views
278 replies
1 rating 2 rating 3 rating 4 rating 5 rating
  • Member since
    January 2001
  • From: Atlanta
  • 11,971 posts
Posted by oltmannd on Tuesday, November 28, 2006 5:51 AM
 futuremodal wrote:

 TimChgo9 wrote:
As I read these threads, I begin to wonder if Open Access is a good idea. Now, I have no railroad freight moving experience at all, all I know is what I read. But it seems, that opening up rail lines to "anyone" who wants to use them, while someone else (be it government, or a corporation, or what have you) maintains the infrastructure seems like a model that could be fraught with problems. While, from what I read, "competition" would increase, and would benefit those captive shippers out there (would it?), it seems like a system asking for trouble. Aside from safety, and maintenance issues, would Open Access mean that any Tom, Dick or Harry that could afford to buy a train, ask for permission to run it on the rails? Let me ask it this way.. Say that I have some money to burn, and I find out that the railroads are now "Open Access" and I have always wanted to buy a train, and run it, and make some money. So, I buy an old locomotive, and some cars, and put myself in business as "TimChgo9 Transportation Company" Now, under OA, would I be able to just put my train on the tracks, and go drumming up customers, or not? How would I be regulated, would the FRA still play a part, or not? Who inspects my equipment, and the training of my Engineers and Brakemen? Or under OA, would all of the regulations be cursory? Or nonexistent? And if the government were to be the ones in control of the infrastructure, would repairs even be made, or would one have to jump through bureaucratic hoops to get something simple done? How long would it take to replace defective rail, or ties, or worn switch points? Not to mention signals, crossing gates, and the like. Since the owner would have no vested interest in a profit, then what would be the motivation to fix anything? AND if there is an accident due to poor infrastructure maintenance, who reimburses the affected carrier, as well as the shipper? What would be the regulating body? Airports can be used by anyone who wants to start an airline, whether they own 2 747's or a bunch of Gulfstream I's, they may be able to start the airline, but they have to submit to the FAA as far as airworthiness of their airplanes, crew training and etc... So, would I have to submit to the FRA, or in lieu of them, would the infrastructure owner demand standards. And who gets priority? The big Railroads, or is it a first come first served.... In other words, if I am there with my old GP40 and my half a dozen cars, can I ask for and get priority over, say, a Chicago to Seattle intermodal? Who would dispatch? Does that fall under "Infrastructure" or would each carrier dispatch their own? I don't see these questions being answered, all I see are one person's apparent dislike, if not loathing of the big railroads, and perhaps his desire for OA is to see the "giants" cut down to size, and his remarks are followed by, either jibes, links to other places, or large, broad based answers that don't deal in nuts and bolts. The theory of a "level playing field" where everyone can "compete fairly" is a nice one.... in theory. But, would it not lead to a period of confusion, over crowding, reduction of service, and possibly a decrease in safety? And if that were the case, would that be good? (Before anyone says anything, I know that some railroads defer maintenance, and have the occasional "safety issue", since I am not a railroader, the railroaders in this forum could probably address the safety thing better than I can) I don't think OA is a magic bullet as some in this forum would like to suggest. It can't be, there is nothing that is a "magic bullet" for anything. Logic would dictate that if OA were implemented, it would lead to a potential mess. While the system we have now works for some, and not really for others, would we be doing rail transportation in this country any favors by going OA?

Did you notice how you framed it all in your last sentence?  E.g. "doing rail transportation.....any favors" rather than "doing US rail shippers any favors".  Just a thought, but why is it that US politicos are supposed to prioritize railroads over rail shippers? 

But to answer your question, yes OA is meant to benefit rail shipping in the US, not necessarily the current rail industry.  Obviously, an unhealthy rail line sector is bad for rail shipping.  But what we are witnessing today is that a strong and powerful rail industry is not necessarily good for rail shipping interests.  So somewhere between having a healthy but abusive rail line sector and an advantageous rail shipping sector but struggling railroad industry is where we're trying to find the utilitarian optimum.

BTW - for the record, I see OA as just one option for bringing comprehensive intramodal rail competition to bear.  Another option I'd favor is keeping the integrated model but making sure all regions of the country have at least three rail service providers, e.g. triopoly or better.  The latter would probably involve a lot of track sharing to prevent overcapitalization.

As for anyone with some bucks buying their own locos and railcars and offering their services (just like many trucking outfits), I'd say the dispensers of scarce capacity would laugh you out of the office, while the overseers of ample capacity would probably consider your bids.  You'd be better off just forming a 3rd party intermodal company like Pacer, then subletting your rail transport needs to one of the presumed established rail service providers - BNSF, UP, KCS, DME, et al.  Other than the largest trucking outfits like JBHunt or UPS, I can't see too much of non rail outfits deciding to run their own trains with an advent of OA.

With true OA, you wouldn't have to buy anything.  The cost of entry into railroading would be near zero.  All the equipment you'd need is available for lease.  All you'd need is a little bit of credit to secure a lease on a locomotive, an engineer's licence and a way to keep HOS records and away you go.   Those operators with a young, non-union work force would be the winners and the traditional carriers would be the losers.  OA would play out exactly like it did in the airline industry with all the "legacy" carriers, that used to "own" the routes going belly up (United, Delta, USAir -twice, American, TWA, PanAm, Continental) as the new guys with low pensions and labor rates took hold (Southwest, JetBlue, Airtran).

If you restrict or regulate access, then it isn't "open" and is much more like the regulated truck companies used to operate.  Notice that most of them have gone by the wayside and have been replaced by JBHunt, Schnieder and other post-regulation upstarts.

But, because of the huge number of OD pairs for rail shipments in the US, the best analogy would be if UPS and FedEx were required to allow "open access" to each others sorting centers.  Completely unworkable.

-Don (Random stuff, mostly about trains - what else? http://blerfblog.blogspot.com/

  • Member since
    August 2003
  • From: Antioch, IL
  • 4,371 posts
Posted by greyhounds on Tuesday, November 28, 2006 12:25 AM
 futuremodal wrote:

But now you're setting up an undefined straw man to try and shoot down the premise.  In other words, you're probably not going to call the railroad to ship 100 tons of flaxseed 50 miles down to the barge port, nor are you going to call J.B. Hunt to ship 10,000 tons of potash from Saskatchewan to Portland OR, nor are you going to call Bubba's Barge line to ship 10 UPS trailers from Dubuque to Memphis...........

No, Dave.  You're the one with the straw man.  Each of the movements you cite has significant competitive alternatives.  Just not the alternatives you (straw man like) cite.

"By many measures, the U.S. freight rail system is the safest, most efficient and cost effective in the world." - Federal Railroad Administration, October, 2009. I'm just your average, everyday, uncivilized howling "anti-government" critic of mass government expenditures for "High Speed Rail" in the US. And I'm gosh darn proud of that.
  • Member since
    September 2006
  • From: Mt. Fuji
  • 1,840 posts
Posted by Datafever on Monday, November 27, 2006 11:43 PM
 futuremodal wrote:

But to answer your question, yes OA is meant to benefit rail shipping in the US, not necessarily the current rail industry.  Obviously, an unhealthy rail line sector is bad for rail shipping.  But what we are witnessing today is that a strong and powerful rail industry is not necessarily good for rail shipping interests.  So somewhere between having a healthy but abusive rail line sector and an advantageous rail shipping sector but struggling railroad industry is where we're trying to find the utilitarian optimum.


And this point may be where a significant amount of disagreement will occur.

The STB has found that NS is the only class 1 railroad that is revenue adequate, which means generating sufficient revenue to not only covering operating costs and maintenance costs, but also the future cost of replacing depreciating assets and building additional capacity.

What we are seeing today is a railroad system that is falling apart because the cost of replacing track is exceedingly high, and maintenance can only do so much to keep the trains rolling.

While the railroad industry may be in much better health than it was 20 years ago, it still has a long way to go to get to the point of being a "strong and powerful rail industry".
"I'm sittin' in a railway station, Got a ticket for my destination..."
  • Member since
    April 2003
  • 305,205 posts
Posted by Anonymous on Monday, November 27, 2006 9:28 PM

 TimChgo9 wrote:
As I read these threads, I begin to wonder if Open Access is a good idea. Now, I have no railroad freight moving experience at all, all I know is what I read. But it seems, that opening up rail lines to "anyone" who wants to use them, while someone else (be it government, or a corporation, or what have you) maintains the infrastructure seems like a model that could be fraught with problems. While, from what I read, "competition" would increase, and would benefit those captive shippers out there (would it?), it seems like a system asking for trouble. Aside from safety, and maintenance issues, would Open Access mean that any Tom, Dick or Harry that could afford to buy a train, ask for permission to run it on the rails? Let me ask it this way.. Say that I have some money to burn, and I find out that the railroads are now "Open Access" and I have always wanted to buy a train, and run it, and make some money. So, I buy an old locomotive, and some cars, and put myself in business as "TimChgo9 Transportation Company" Now, under OA, would I be able to just put my train on the tracks, and go drumming up customers, or not? How would I be regulated, would the FRA still play a part, or not? Who inspects my equipment, and the training of my Engineers and Brakemen? Or under OA, would all of the regulations be cursory? Or nonexistent? And if the government were to be the ones in control of the infrastructure, would repairs even be made, or would one have to jump through bureaucratic hoops to get something simple done? How long would it take to replace defective rail, or ties, or worn switch points? Not to mention signals, crossing gates, and the like. Since the owner would have no vested interest in a profit, then what would be the motivation to fix anything? AND if there is an accident due to poor infrastructure maintenance, who reimburses the affected carrier, as well as the shipper? What would be the regulating body? Airports can be used by anyone who wants to start an airline, whether they own 2 747's or a bunch of Gulfstream I's, they may be able to start the airline, but they have to submit to the FAA as far as airworthiness of their airplanes, crew training and etc... So, would I have to submit to the FRA, or in lieu of them, would the infrastructure owner demand standards. And who gets priority? The big Railroads, or is it a first come first served.... In other words, if I am there with my old GP40 and my half a dozen cars, can I ask for and get priority over, say, a Chicago to Seattle intermodal? Who would dispatch? Does that fall under "Infrastructure" or would each carrier dispatch their own? I don't see these questions being answered, all I see are one person's apparent dislike, if not loathing of the big railroads, and perhaps his desire for OA is to see the "giants" cut down to size, and his remarks are followed by, either jibes, links to other places, or large, broad based answers that don't deal in nuts and bolts. The theory of a "level playing field" where everyone can "compete fairly" is a nice one.... in theory. But, would it not lead to a period of confusion, over crowding, reduction of service, and possibly a decrease in safety? And if that were the case, would that be good? (Before anyone says anything, I know that some railroads defer maintenance, and have the occasional "safety issue", since I am not a railroader, the railroaders in this forum could probably address the safety thing better than I can) I don't think OA is a magic bullet as some in this forum would like to suggest. It can't be, there is nothing that is a "magic bullet" for anything. Logic would dictate that if OA were implemented, it would lead to a potential mess. While the system we have now works for some, and not really for others, would we be doing rail transportation in this country any favors by going OA?

Did you notice how you framed it all in your last sentence?  E.g. "doing rail transportation.....any favors" rather than "doing US rail shippers any favors".  Just a thought, but why is it that US politicos are supposed to prioritize railroads over rail shippers? 

But to answer your question, yes OA is meant to benefit rail shipping in the US, not necessarily the current rail industry.  Obviously, an unhealthy rail line sector is bad for rail shipping.  But what we are witnessing today is that a strong and powerful rail industry is not necessarily good for rail shipping interests.  So somewhere between having a healthy but abusive rail line sector and an advantageous rail shipping sector but struggling railroad industry is where we're trying to find the utilitarian optimum.

BTW - for the record, I see OA as just one option for bringing comprehensive intramodal rail competition to bear.  Another option I'd favor is keeping the integrated model but making sure all regions of the country have at least three rail service providers, e.g. triopoly or better.  The latter would probably involve a lot of track sharing to prevent overcapitalization.

As for anyone with some bucks buying their own locos and railcars and offering their services (just like many trucking outfits), I'd say the dispensers of scarce capacity would laugh you out of the office, while the overseers of ample capacity would probably consider your bids.  You'd be better off just forming a 3rd party intermodal company like Pacer, then subletting your rail transport needs to one of the presumed established rail service providers - BNSF, UP, KCS, DME, et al.  Other than the largest trucking outfits like JBHunt or UPS, I can't see too much of non rail outfits deciding to run their own trains with an advent of OA.

  • Member since
    April 2003
  • 305,205 posts
Posted by Anonymous on Monday, November 27, 2006 9:07 PM

 1435mm wrote:
 Datafever wrote:
There are a couple of points that keep getting made over and over that just kind of nag at the back of my cognitive processing.  These points frequently seem to be used to bolster each other and they do provide a backdrop for each other.  These points are:

1) Trucks are not (always) a competition for trains.

2) Imported goods are never captive.

Both statements are fairly accurate.  The argument seems to go something like this:

Domestic manufacturers that are captive shippers are at an economic disadvantage to imported goods.  Since imported goods will get low competitive rail rates while domestic manufacturers (at least the ones for whom truck transport is not an alternative) are likely to be tied to only one Class 1 railroad and therefore pay exorbitant monopolistic rates.  This gives imported goods an economic advantage over domestic goods and contributes to the trade imbalance.

And yet, what types of commodities cannot reasonably be transported by truck?  Minerals (such as coal and potash) are brought up as an example.  Grains (such as wheat and corn) are another example.  Liquids (such as ethanol).

But these are not the types of commodities that are generally imported.  Most imported goods can generally be reasonably transported by truck or rail.  Domestic manufacturers of those types of goods can also use truck or rail for transport and therefore they are not captive shippers.  Therefore they are not paying outrageous monopolistic rates for transportation of their goods.  And therefore, they are on level playing ground economically.

I don't know that I have done a very good job of expressing what I wanted to say, but hopefully my point has been made.



Notwithstanding the "argument", it rests on a false premise, that trucks and railroads each have an impregnable market segment only they can fill.  Coal, grain, potash, ethanol are all not only "reasonably" transported by truck but in enormous volumes and often for some surprisingly long distances.  Transportation is too complex to reduce to simple generalizations about the market-matched niches of transportation modes, and the result of that reduction has been and continues to be a lot of bad public policy.  There are plenty of examples of coal moving 500 miles by truck and 5 miles by train, for instance.

But now you're setting up an undefined straw man to try and shoot down the premise.  The combination of shipping volumes, distance, and time sensitivity generally dictate which mode is chosen for the main haul.  Are you talking about 10,000 tons of coal/grain/potash/et al, or are you talking about a few hundred tons of coal/grain/potash/et al?  Are you talking a few hundred miles or a few thousand miles?  Once you determine your product's shipping characteristic, then you decide how it moves - other than intermodal combo's, you're not going to sub an alternate mode in place of the optimal mode.

In other words, you're probably not going to call the railroad to ship 100 tons of flaxseed 50 miles down to the barge port, nor are you going to call J.B. Hunt to ship 10,000 tons of potash from Saskatchewan to Portland OR, nor are you going to call Bubba's Barge line to ship 10 UPS trailers from Dubuque to Memphis...........

  • Member since
    September 2006
  • From: Mt. Fuji
  • 1,840 posts
Posted by Datafever on Monday, November 27, 2006 4:24 PM
 Lee Koch wrote:


I have another question, though. I've read alot of theory and some statistics on this thread, and now I'd like to see some factual examples (please, no links!) of pricing for captive shippers compared to rates for non-captive shippers and compared to other modes of transportation (primarily trucking). I suspect that the price per ton-mile is lower for almost anything by rail, even for the so called captive shipper, than it would be by truck, but this is just an assumption, as I have no facts to back it up with.


I don't have information about trucking.  For captive vs. non-captive shippers, here is an example:

To ship grain from Minot, ND to Portland, OR, the cost per ton-mile has dropped from about 3.4 cents in 1997 to about 2.9 cents in 2004.  Minot is served by only one Class 1 railroad.

To ship grain from Sioux Falls, SD to Portland, OR, the cost per ton-mile has dropped from about 1.9 cents in 1997 to about 1.5 cents in 2004.  Sioux Falls is served by two Class 1 railroads.

I think that it is fair to say that if a shipper in Minot could ship grain to Portland by truck for less than 3 cents per ton-mile, then they would be doing so.
"I'm sittin' in a railway station, Got a ticket for my destination..."
  • Member since
    October 2004
  • 3,190 posts
Posted by MichaelSol on Monday, November 27, 2006 1:54 PM
Don't make it too complicated. You can pose as many constraints as you like or look at the lowest common denominator or worst case scenario if you wish. Taking that approach will answer the questions for you. We wouldn't have the Staggers Act in the first place if Congress and the industry took that approach.

Assume a level of "reasonablenss." That's always a good place to start.

What do you think would be reasonable?

Suppose Open Access meant, in general, open access with the following service providers, BNSF, UP, CSX, NS, CN, CP, KCS, NdM, MRL, DME. Would that idea suggest answers to your questions? Each could also bid as operators on the line or system segments. An alternative, each could be a proportionate owner of the system, and they would select, bid out, contract out maintenance and operations.


  • Member since
    August 2002
  • From: Along the BNSF "East End"... :-)
  • 915 posts
Posted by TimChgo9 on Monday, November 27, 2006 1:10 PM
As I read these threads, I begin to wonder if Open Access is a good idea. Now, I have no railroad freight moving experience at all, all I know is what I read. But it seems, that opening up rail lines to "anyone" who wants to use them, while someone else (be it government, or a corporation, or what have you) maintains the infrastructure seems like a model that could be fraught with problems. While, from what I read, "competition" would increase, and would benefit those captive shippers out there (would it?), it seems like a system asking for trouble.

Aside from safety, and maintenance issues, would Open Access mean that any Tom, Dick or Harry that could afford to buy a train, ask for permission to run it on the rails?

Let me ask it this way.. Say that I have some money to burn, and I find out that the railroads are now "Open Access" and I have always wanted to buy a train, and run it, and make some money. So, I buy an old locomotive, and some cars, and put myself in business as "TimChgo9 Transportation Company" Now, under OA, would I be able to just put my train on the tracks, and go drumming up customers, or not? How would I be regulated, would the FRA still play a part, or not? Who inspects my equipment, and the training of my Engineers and Brakemen? Or under OA, would all of the regulations be cursory? Or nonexistent? And if the government were to be the ones in control of the infrastructure, would repairs even be made, or would one have to jump through bureaucratic hoops to get something simple done? How long would it take to replace defective rail, or ties, or worn switch points? Not to mention signals, crossing gates, and the like. Since the owner would have no vested interest in a profit, then what would be the motivation to fix anything? AND if there is an accident due to poor infrastructure maintenance, who reimburses the affected carrier, as well as the shipper?

What would be the regulating body? Airports can be used by anyone who wants to start an airline, whether they own 2 747's or a bunch of Gulfstream I's, they may be able to start the airline, but they have to submit to the FAA as far as airworthiness of their airplanes, crew training and etc... So, would I have to submit to the FRA, or in lieu of them, would the infrastructure owner demand standards. And who gets priority? The big Railroads, or is it a first come first served.... In other words, if I am there with my old GP40 and my half a dozen cars, can I ask for and get priority over, say, a Chicago to Seattle intermodal? Who would dispatch? Does that fall under "Infrastructure" or would each carrier dispatch their own?

I don't see these questions being answered, all I see are one person's apparent dislike, if not loathing of the big railroads, and perhaps his desire for OA is to see the "giants" cut down to size, and his remarks are followed by, either jibes, links to other places, or large, broad based answers that don't deal in nuts and bolts.

The theory of a "level playing field" where everyone can "compete fairly" is a nice one.... in theory. But, would it not lead to a period of confusion, over crowding, reduction of service, and possibly a decrease in safety? And if that were the case, would that be good? (Before anyone says anything, I know that some railroads defer maintenance, and have the occasional "safety issue", since I am not a railroader, the railroaders in this forum could probably address the safety thing better than I can)

I don't think OA is a magic bullet as some in this forum would like to suggest. It can't be, there is nothing that is a "magic bullet" for anything. Logic would dictate that if OA were implemented, it would lead to a potential mess. While the system we have now works for some, and not really for others, would we be doing rail transportation in this country any favors by going OA?
"Chairman of the Awkward Squad" "We live in an amazing, amazing world that is just wasted on the biggest generation of spoiled idiots." Flashing red lights are a warning.....heed it. " I don't give a hoot about what people have to say, I'm laughing as I'm analyzed" What if the "hokey pokey" is what it's all about?? View photos at: http://www.eyefetch.com/profile.aspx?user=timChgo9
  • Member since
    December 2001
  • From: Crozet, VA
  • 1,049 posts
Posted by bobwilcox on Monday, November 27, 2006 12:49 PM
Rail customers have two other alternatives beside using another railroad or using a truck.  Many rail customers have more than one manufacturing plant making the same product.  If the railroad serving their widget factory in MI charges too much they can fullfill the order from their midget factory in TX. The railroads serving the plants in MI and TX need to understand the threat posed by the other source for widgets. If an electric utility in Wuhan finds to cost of BC coal too high he can switch to fuel oil from Kuwait.  The CPR needs to understand the threat of product competition when they make their rates.

Bob
  • Member since
    September 2005
  • From: Good Old Germany
  • 159 posts
Posted by Flint Hills Tex on Monday, November 27, 2006 11:05 AM
Datafever wrote:

"Domestic manufacturers that are captive shippers are at an economic disadvantage to imported goods. Since imported goods will get low competitive rail rates while domestic manufacturers (at least the ones for whom truck transport is not an alternative) are likely to be tied to only one Class 1 railroad and therefore pay exorbitant monopolistic rates. This gives imported goods an economic advantage over domestic goods and contributes to the trade imbalance.

And yet, what types of commodities cannot reasonably be transported by truck? Minerals (such as coal and potash) are brought up as an example. Grains (such as wheat and corn) are another example. Liquids (such as ethanol).

But these are not the types of commodities that are generally imported. Most imported goods can generally be reasonably transported by truck or rail. Domestic manufacturers of those types of goods can also use truck or rail for transport and therefore they are not captive shippers. Therefore they are not paying outrageous monopolistic rates for transportation of their goods. And therefore, they are on level playing ground economically."


I think you've raised a very good question, to which none of the replies to date has supplied an adequate answer. And it's not like this question hasn't been asked before on this thread: WHY do we need OA, and WHO will benefit from it?

If it is to be the captive shipper, then you have to ask yourself whether appeasing such a small market segment truly justifies the radical infringement of property rights which would be required to be effectively implement OA.

I have another question, though. I've read alot of theory and some statistics on this thread, and now I'd like to see some factual examples (please, no links!) of pricing for captive shippers compared to rates for non-captive shippers and compared to other modes of transportation (primarily trucking). I suspect that the price per ton-mile is lower for almost anything by rail, even for the so called captive shipper, than it would be by truck, but this is just an assumption, as I have no facts to back it up with.

If, however, my assumption is correct, then captive shippers are just belly-aching because they are paying more than other rail shippers, and not, as they would have us believe, because they have no other alternatives.
Out here we...pay no attention to titles or honors or whatever because we have found they don't measure a man.... A man is what he is, and what he is shows in his actions. I do not ask where a man came from or what he was...none of that is important. -Louis Lámour "Shalako"
  • Member since
    August 2003
  • From: Antioch, IL
  • 4,371 posts
Posted by greyhounds on Saturday, November 25, 2006 7:39 PM

Yes, I was talking about movement from the elevator.

They used to lay temporary railroad tracks in sugar cane fields and load directly into diminutive trains.  Aside from that, farm products have always come out of the fields on somebody's back, in a horse drawn wagon, or in a truck.

"By many measures, the U.S. freight rail system is the safest, most efficient and cost effective in the world." - Federal Railroad Administration, October, 2009. I'm just your average, everyday, uncivilized howling "anti-government" critic of mass government expenditures for "High Speed Rail" in the US. And I'm gosh darn proud of that.
  • Member since
    September 2006
  • From: Mt. Fuji
  • 1,840 posts
Posted by Datafever on Saturday, November 25, 2006 5:16 PM
 greyhounds wrote:

 Datafever wrote:

And yet, what types of commodities cannot reasonably be transported by truck?  Minerals (such as coal and potash) are brought up as an example.  Grains (such as wheat and corn) are another example.  Liquids (such as ethanol).


Oh, they move by truck just fine.  On a tonnage basis, trucks move 2/3 of the US field crops.  Less than 18% of the tons move by rail.  Now that changes when you measure by ton-miles instead of tons, but since most of the field crops don't move very far, trucks dominate.  Ethanol and coal are also trucked.  For more info on the crops see:

http://www.fapri.missouri.edu/outreach/publications/2004/FAPRI_UMC_Briefing_Paper_04_04.pdf


At one level, don't trucks move almost 100% of field crops for at least some distance?  It may only be a distance of 5 to 20 miles, but I don't think that there are too many places where crop is loaded directly from field to rail. Black Eye [B)]  Big Smile [:D]
"I'm sittin' in a railway station, Got a ticket for my destination..."
  • Member since
    September 2006
  • From: Mt. Fuji
  • 1,840 posts
Posted by Datafever on Saturday, November 25, 2006 5:08 PM
 1435mm wrote:


Notwithstanding the "argument", it rests on a false premise, that trucks and railroads each have an impregnable market segment only they can fill.  Coal, grain, potash, ethanol are all not only "reasonably" transported by truck but in enormous volumes and often for some surprisingly long distances.  Transportation is too complex to reduce to simple generalizations about the market-matched niches of transportation modes, and the result of that reduction has been and continues to be a lot of bad public policy.  There are plenty of examples of coal moving 500 miles by truck and 5 miles by train, for instance.

Take a look at the Bureau of Transportation Statistics Commodity Flow Surveys by Mode.

S. Hadid

A market segment does not need to be impregnable for it to be non-competitive.  If it costs $5 a ton-mile to ship a product by rail and $15 a ton-mile to ship by truck, then what shipper would not prefer rail over truck?  Indeed, if demand for that product drops off significantly when transportation costs exceed $8 a ton-mile, then effectively truck transport is not a competition to rail transport for that product.

I will agree that generalizations are used much too often.  That is why I try to avoid words like 'always' and 'never'.  But market niches do exist.  There are advantages and disadvantages to each kind of transport.  For example, air freight is fast, but expensive.

I think that the railroads are in a transitional period right now, adjusting to market conditions to find the niche in which they are the most profitable.
"I'm sittin' in a railway station, Got a ticket for my destination..."
  • Member since
    September 2006
  • From: Mt. Fuji
  • 1,840 posts
Posted by Datafever on Saturday, November 25, 2006 4:52 PM
greyhounds and 1435mm:

I understand what you are both saying, I think.  Basically, your premise is that truck transport is always a viable alternative to rail transport and that shippers choose rail transport because it is economically advantageous for them to do so.  There are some who would disagree with that position, but that is only incidental to the point that I was hoping to make.

Some shippers are considered to be captive because they pay high tranportation rates (or because they have only one direct connection to a Class 1 railroad).  These tend to be shippers of bulk products.  These bulk products are not products that are generally imported.  Therefore it cannot be said that the higher rates are causing these domestic shippers an unfair economic disadvantage compared to foreign manufacturers.
"I'm sittin' in a railway station, Got a ticket for my destination..."
  • Member since
    August 2003
  • From: Antioch, IL
  • 4,371 posts
Posted by greyhounds on Saturday, November 25, 2006 3:34 PM

 Datafever wrote:

And yet, what types of commodities cannot reasonably be transported by truck?  Minerals (such as coal and potash) are brought up as an example.  Grains (such as wheat and corn) are another example.  Liquids (such as ethanol).


Oh, they move by truck just fine.  On a tonnage basis, trucks move 2/3 of the US field crops.  Less than 18% of the tons move by rail.  Now that changes when you measure by ton-miles instead of tons, but since most of the field crops don't move very far, trucks dominate.  Ethanol and coal are also trucked.  For more info on the crops see:

http://www.fapri.missouri.edu/outreach/publications/2004/FAPRI_UMC_Briefing_Paper_04_04.pdf

"By many measures, the U.S. freight rail system is the safest, most efficient and cost effective in the world." - Federal Railroad Administration, October, 2009. I'm just your average, everyday, uncivilized howling "anti-government" critic of mass government expenditures for "High Speed Rail" in the US. And I'm gosh darn proud of that.
  • Member since
    April 2003
  • 305,205 posts
Posted by Anonymous on Saturday, November 25, 2006 3:10 PM
 Datafever wrote:
There are a couple of points that keep getting made over and over that just kind of nag at the back of my cognitive processing.  These points frequently seem to be used to bolster each other and they do provide a backdrop for each other.  These points are:

1) Trucks are not (always) a competition for trains.

2) Imported goods are never captive.

Both statements are fairly accurate.  The argument seems to go something like this:

Domestic manufacturers that are captive shippers are at an economic disadvantage to imported goods.  Since imported goods will get low competitive rail rates while domestic manufacturers (at least the ones for whom truck transport is not an alternative) are likely to be tied to only one Class 1 railroad and therefore pay exorbitant monopolistic rates.  This gives imported goods an economic advantage over domestic goods and contributes to the trade imbalance.

And yet, what types of commodities cannot reasonably be transported by truck?  Minerals (such as coal and potash) are brought up as an example.  Grains (such as wheat and corn) are another example.  Liquids (such as ethanol).

But these are not the types of commodities that are generally imported.  Most imported goods can generally be reasonably transported by truck or rail.  Domestic manufacturers of those types of goods can also use truck or rail for transport and therefore they are not captive shippers.  Therefore they are not paying outrageous monopolistic rates for transportation of their goods.  And therefore, they are on level playing ground economically.

I don't know that I have done a very good job of expressing what I wanted to say, but hopefully my point has been made.



Notwithstanding the "argument", it rests on a false premise, that trucks and railroads each have an impregnable market segment only they can fill.  Coal, grain, potash, ethanol are all not only "reasonably" transported by truck but in enormous volumes and often for some surprisingly long distances.  Transportation is too complex to reduce to simple generalizations about the market-matched niches of transportation modes, and the result of that reduction has been and continues to be a lot of bad public policy.  There are plenty of examples of coal moving 500 miles by truck and 5 miles by train, for instance.

Take a look at the Bureau of Transportation Statistics Commodity Flow Surveys by Mode.

S. Hadid
  • Member since
    September 2006
  • From: Mt. Fuji
  • 1,840 posts
Posted by Datafever on Saturday, November 25, 2006 2:35 PM
There are a couple of points that keep getting made over and over that just kind of nag at the back of my cognitive processing.  These points frequently seem to be used to bolster each other and they do provide a backdrop for each other.  These points are:

1) Trucks are not (always) a competition for trains.

2) Imported goods are never captive.

Both statements are fairly accurate.  The argument seems to go something like this:

Domestic manufacturers that are captive shippers are at an economic disadvantage to imported goods.  Since imported goods will get low competitive rail rates while domestic manufacturers (at least the ones for whom truck transport is not an alternative) are likely to be tied to only one Class 1 railroad and therefore pay exorbitant monopolistic rates.  This gives imported goods an economic advantage over domestic goods and contributes to the trade imbalance.

And yet, what types of commodities cannot reasonably be transported by truck?  Minerals (such as coal and potash) are brought up as an example.  Grains (such as wheat and corn) are another example.  Liquids (such as ethanol).

But these are not the types of commodities that are generally imported.  Most imported goods can generally be reasonably transported by truck or rail.  Domestic manufacturers of those types of goods can also use truck or rail for transport and therefore they are not captive shippers.  Therefore they are not paying outrageous monopolistic rates for transportation of their goods.  And therefore, they are on level playing ground economically.

I don't know that I have done a very good job of expressing what I wanted to say, but hopefully my point has been made.

"I'm sittin' in a railway station, Got a ticket for my destination..."
  • Member since
    October 2004
  • 3,190 posts
Posted by MichaelSol on Wednesday, November 22, 2006 10:03 PM
 greyhounds wrote:

As far as large railroads being less efficient than smaller ones,  the author cited by MS, Kent T. Healy, has been deceased for 20 years.  He studied an industry that no longer exists in the same form.  I'm sure he did good analysis, but it's relavancy today is questionable.  Tremendous productivity gains in railroading came from deregulation.  And the author's work concentrated on the regulated era, which induced a lot of inefficiencies into railroading.

If so, then looking at deregulated industries should shed some light on whether large or smaller corporations are more efficient. If the proposition is that post-deregulation, railroads look more like other corporations, then note that Healy was drawing his analysis from work done on unregulated industries, and only confirmed that railroads behaved the same in terms of efficiency related to size. Regulation had nothing to do with it.

Modern analysis has confirmed that not only are there inherent diseconomies of scale in industrial corporations -- Healy simply showed that railroads, even as regulated, obeyed general economic laws -- but that as the result of improvements in communications and IT technology, the optimum size of corporations is becoming smaller, not larger.

This would not be the first instance that the rail industry got it backwards by thinking as some do that IT technology enables larger corporations to be more efficient. This is, after all, the same industry that thought the Staggers Act would allow them to raise rates.

Maybe PCs and IT do allow larger corporations to be more efficient, but the same technology allows smaller corporations the same advantages. The technology, in that instance, does not change the concept of diseconomies of scale, rather, makes them more, rather than less significant compared to a hypothetical smaller competitor.

Today, the little guy's Dell is just as good as the GM VP's Dell. Forty years ago, there was a world of difference between what the GM guy had available and what the little guy had.

In 1968, I had a choice between my yellow, finely-machined Pickett slide rule, or a third generation IBM 360 identical to the one MILW upgraded to that year. From experience, I will tell you exactly what the difference is between these eras, then and now.

The false premise offered by BobWilcox and greyhounds is that PC and IT technology offers advantages to large corporate enterprises. Yet, the fact that $600 now purchases 10,000 times the computing power of an IBM 360, operates in favor of the smaller, not the larger, enterprise in terms of leveling the competitive advantage formerly offered to large corporations which alone could afford the high investment and ongoing costs required by a 360 installation.

The IBM 360 created an economy of scale that favored the larger corporate enterprise at the very time that Healy was doing his landmark study. Since then, the desktop PC has destroyed that economy of scale. This has to shift the threshold of any diseconomy of scale down, not up.

Healy's results would now show a shift further in favor of smaller railroad companies, as the result of both deregulation and IT technology. Recent econometric analysis supports that view.

"As for the future, the stock market does not expect the largest firms to outperform smaller firms. The stock market valuation of the largest firms, relative to smaller firms, has declined sharply between 1964 and 1998 (Farrell 1998). In 1964 the largest 20 firms comprised 44 per cent of total stock market capitalisation in the United States; in 1998 they accounted for 19.5 per cent. Market value primarily reflects future growth and profit expectations, and thus the market is increasingly sceptical of large firms’ ability to compete with smaller firms. This could be due to industrial evolution, but if it is assumed that diseconomies of scale do not exist, then the largest 20 firms should presumably be able to compensate for a relative decline in their mature businesses by effortlessly growing new businesses.

"A study of firms on the New York stock exchange (Ibbotson Associates 1999, 127-143) similarly showed that small firms outperformed large firms between 1926 and 1998. The total annual shareholder return over the period was 12.1 per cent for the largest size decile and 13.7 per cent for the second largest size decile. It increased steadily to 21.0 per cent for the smallest size decile (p. 129). The real return to shareholders after adjustment for risk (using the capital asset pricing model) was -0.28 per cent for decile 1, +0.18 per cent for decile 2 and rising steadily to +4.35 per cent for decile 10 (p. 140). Note, however, that market capitalisation was used as the definition of size in this study.

"The above evidence shows that concentration in the manufacturing sector—defined as the share of value added, employment, assets or market capitalisation held by large firms—has changed little or has declined over  much of the last century. The size of large manufacturing firms has kept pace with the overall growth of the manufacturing part of the economy since the 1960s in value-added terms, but has declined in employment terms since 1979 (and has declined relative to the total US corporate sector and the global corporate sector). This indicates that there is a limit to firm size and that this limit may be decreasing in absolute terms, all of which supports the research findings of this thesis."

Bureaucratic Limits of Firm Size: Empirical Analysis Using Transaction Cost Economics, PhD Thesis, Staffan Canbäck, Henley Management College, Brunel University, February 2002.

http://canback.com/dissertation.pdf

The OA argument may be that the rail industry, having already destroyed its ability to operate at societally acceptable levels of efficiency -- that is, maximized -- might be, for its own good, broken into a model that permits recovery of those efficiencies; whereas arbitrary break-up of the industry into more efficient independent units may be impossible at this point.

 

  • Member since
    March 2002
  • 9,265 posts
Posted by edblysard on Wednesday, November 22, 2006 6:39 PM

You touched on one of the major reason the UP melt down began in Houston…the attempt by UP to “standardize” the old SP yard system, Englewood in particular, into the UP culture way too fast…

Each terminal, and each yard develops around the customers it serves, and not all customer are the same.

Each terminal manager and every corridor manager who have held their position for any length of time know who needs what service, when and why.

Attempting to make those SP customers accept what they, (UP) though they should have, and trying to change the culture instead of allowing it to adapt plugged the yards with trains.

The rest of the story is well known…

 

Ed

23 17 46 11

  • Member since
    September 2006
  • From: Mt. Fuji
  • 1,840 posts
Posted by Datafever on Wednesday, November 22, 2006 2:16 PM
Regarding the inefficiencies of scale that may have been created by railroad mega-mergers:

My suspicion is that most of those inefficiencies result from attempts to standardize operations across the entire system.  Two terminal areas may very well each require slightly different operating procedures to maximize productivity.  Therefore, the more terminal areas that a railroad serves, the greater the likelihood that inefficiencies will be brought into play if standardization is implemented system-wide.

Effective management is the best solution.  If each terminal area is handled as a quasi-separate business unit and allowed to operate in the most efficient manner, then large railroads will not by less efficient than smaller railroads, but can effectively have overall increased efficiency.

"I'm sittin' in a railway station, Got a ticket for my destination..."
  • Member since
    September 2006
  • From: Mt. Fuji
  • 1,840 posts
Posted by Datafever on Wednesday, November 22, 2006 2:04 PM
As I continue to read about open access, I get the feeling that open access is a solution looking for a problem to solve.  I may be crazy, but isn't the normal way to solve problems to start by looking at the problem and then finding a solution?

Do the railroads have some problems?  Let's not hide our head in the sands.  Yes, there are some.

1) Some shippers are captive.  Is this a problem for the railroads?  If it isn't now, it will be when those shippers manage to get enough clout to cause Congress to take action.

2) Large railroads may have created inefficiencies of scale.  Are there significant differences between one large merged railroad and several smaller railroads being held by a single holding company?

3) Lack of competition may stifle innovation.

I'm sure that there are others, but those are the only ones that I can think of off the top of my head right now.  Would anyone be willing to elaborate on these problems, or any other problems they see that the railroads are facing?

"I'm sittin' in a railway station, Got a ticket for my destination..."
  • Member since
    October 2004
  • 3,190 posts
Posted by MichaelSol on Tuesday, November 21, 2006 12:48 PM

Well, I am seeing a little bit of today's "Dilbert" in the discussion.

Anyway, looking at the "Dark 70s":

GDP Growth (Real)
1940s5.6%
1950s 4.1%
1960s 4.4%
1970s 3.2%
1980s 3.0%
1990s 3.1%
2000s 2.7%

The "Dark Days" of the 1970s were "less dark" in terms of economic growth than the 1990s. Railroads were reaching their former WWII tonnage highs by the mid-1970s, and these tonnage highs were substantially higher than they carried during the 1950s and 1960s.

As near as I can tell, the argument is:
1) we never heard of Kent Healy
2) we haven't read his study and don't actually know what it says
3) but, we know it's wrong
4) because "things" have changed.
5) railroad economists with strong economic and engineering backgrounds in the rail industry don't understand the industry,
6) No, we have no actual data for anything we say.

Although regulation is typically blamed for the plight of railroads in the 1970s, and deregulation "unleashed" productivity surges -- although now, I see PCs and the internet are at least partly responsible -- there is little support for this.

Actual economic growth in the 1970s was not bad. But three business models got into trouble in that era -- railroading, automotive, and aircraft manufacturing. For examples, Rock Island, Chrysler, and Lockheed.

From the standpoint of regulation as a causation, it probably wasn't much of a factor compared to other, more significant, factors. Rock Island operated in a regulated, competitive environment. Chrysler operated in a highly competitive, deregulated environment. Lockheed operated in a highly subsidized environment. You could not find three more divergent business models -- all suffering the same problem. Regulation obviously was not the commonality. However, a high capital need during a time of high inflation, and historically high interest rates to obtain that capital was a significant and compelling commonality.

Altman-Z analysis of U.S. corporations in 1979 showed a predictive power of over 90% for economic distress for those corporations with a score less 1.8 or less. But the Altman-Z score is derived from balance sheets and income statements, and appears historically entirely independent of regulatory considerations. And the score, and the basis for the score, does not appear to have substantially drifted -- that is, the elements that determined corporate health in 1970 are identical to the factors that determine corporate health in 2006.

The point? Standard econometric analysis suggests that corporations still succeed the old-fashioned way -- continually improving productivity and passing the savings along to customers. Or fail in the same fashion by being unable or unwilling to do so.

Now, has IT "revolutionized" something? Technological change has driven industrial productivity for over 150 years. There is absolutely nothing new about that. Productivity generally increases every year in every industry unless someone is screwing up. A productivity curve for steam engines on American railroads, for instance, shows a regular rate of marginal improvement in economic efficiency of maintenance and operation in every year after 1920. Did dieselization change the curve? Nope.

I have here a mechanical Burroughs adding calculator. It has 150 keys, and you pull a handle to perform the operation. Anecdotally, I am told this machine enabled the railroad to replace three clerks with one. That was 80 years ago. Did the advent of the electronic calculator again improve productivity? No doubt. Did the IBM 360 computer do what Ken Strawbridge describes above? Yes, and it did so for MILW and CNW in 1959, forty seven years before Ken Strawbridge discovered he could do it just yesterday on a desktop. Is that remarkable progress? Not really. It's normal progress.

Does software and IT improve productivity?  Well, the evidence is spotty on that. Some studies have reported declining productivity. The point is that in order to constitute something remarkable, the productivity increase has to be marginally greater than the historical rate of productivity improvement which almost always exists continuously in any forward looking industry. There is no evidence that has happened in the rail industry as a specific response to IT acquisition. None whatsoever. These operations have always been improving, and IT would be a normal part of that process -- a process that was occuring when Kent Healy was a little boy, when Healy did his studies, and will be occuring in the next generation as well.

So, does any of that change what Kent Healy looked at in terms of general economic operating principles in the rail industry?

Not one iota.

  • Member since
    September 2005
  • From: Good Old Germany
  • 159 posts
Posted by Flint Hills Tex on Tuesday, November 21, 2006 10:21 AM
MichaelSol wrote:

"'Lee Koch wrote: I do not totally agree with you, even though what you've written may be accepted economic theory. I believe that, precisely by virtue of their size, the Class I RRs are able to offer efficient, inexpensive long distance intermodal service because they are able to pool their resources and economize both overhead and time. According to your theory, RRs would function better if there were more and smaller RRs.

This scenario brings us back to the days of the alphabet route, with time being lost to multiple interchanges and money being lost to increased accounting neccessary!'

Well, it's not my theory, but rather the results of a study by a well known railroad economist. Kent Healy has probably done more statistical work on post WWII railroads than anyone.

I have seen the results of that study confirmed by a private study done on the BN ca. 1978 comparing its economic performance with those of its substantially smaller predecessors.

There are no doubt inefficiencies at a small scale due to increased accounting and multiple interchanges. However, to argue there are no inefficiencies of scale .... "

Michael, don't misunderstand me, I'm not arguing that there are no inefficiencies of scale in today's class I RRs. If I were, then I would not have quoted the article on NS's regional business units. What I am stating is that I do not believe that a large RR must, by virtue of its size, be inefficient. I'm convinced that prudent managment can counterbalance the effects of the inefficiency of scale. At the same time, I also believe that today's Class Is are better able to efficiently meet the transportation needs of their customers than the conglomeration of small regional RRs that we had in the mid 20th century.

Mr. Healy's research was done before our time, and there was no way that he could forsee the developments in today's transportation market. Sure, post WWII railroads became bloated, and then they failed. Why? They rode on the wave of the post-war economic boom, expanding their operations and their physical plant, and failed to predict how automobiles, air traffic and trucking would affect their business. Back when railroading was the only (transportation) show in town, the RRs' decision to expand made perfect sense. But once they lost their market share, then their size became their handicap.

And I dare say, a study done in 1978, the Dark Age of North American railroading, comparing a gargantuan RR to smaller PREDECESSORS (which, I assume, therefore, were no longer in existence at the time of the study), could produce no other result than that the RRs were suffering under an inefficiency of scale.
Out here we...pay no attention to titles or honors or whatever because we have found they don't measure a man.... A man is what he is, and what he is shows in his actions. I do not ask where a man came from or what he was...none of that is important. -Louis Lámour "Shalako"
  • Member since
    August 2003
  • From: Antioch, IL
  • 4,371 posts
Posted by greyhounds on Tuesday, November 21, 2006 12:38 AM

Well, as far as IT productivity improvements ... There are a lot of people not employed as clerks by the railroads because of IT productivity improvements. 

Just as an example from another industry, I was recently task to produce a 10% ramdom sample of a customer base.  In less than 45 minutes it went from "Hey, we need you to do this" to having the sample, including account number, name, addrerss, city, state, zip +4, ready.  That was over 230,000 randomly selected records.  You couldn't even try such a thing without the IT productivity.   Common sense needs to be applied to evaluations of things like IT productivity.  Without it you'd have clerks reaching into jars drawing out random account numbers, then copying the names and addresses onto some endless list that was 230,000 names long.  It would take an army of clerks.  And a couple of 'em would spill coffee on the list. 

As far as large railroads being less efficient than smaller ones,  the author cited by MS, Kent T. Healy, has been deceased for 20 years.  He studied an industry that no longer exists in the same form.  I'm sure he did good analysis, but it's relavancy today is questionable.  Tremendous productivity gains in railroading came from deregulation.  And the author's work concentrated on the regulated era, which induced a lot of inefficiencies into railroading.

While the UP has had continuing problems digesting its acquisistions, it has improved its operating ratio by five points from 3Q2005 to 3Q2006.  Are their problems the result of their large size, on some inadequate management?  We're gonna' see.

And the Southern, N&W (the old one), Central of Georgia, Nickle Plate, Wabash, and part of the Pennsylvania, Reading, New York Central, etc. all went together to produce a very efficient larger Norfolk Southern railroad.

As did the CB&Q, GN, NP, SP&S, SLSF, and ATSF.

And the best growth into a larger system of all has to be the Canadian National's acquisisitons of the IC, WC and DM&IR (I'll count the GTW as already having been part of CN).  The CN's operating ratio in the 3rd quarter was in the mid 50's.  That's literally unbelievably good.  And they operate a huge, expanded, system that goes from Hallifax to New Oleans to Prince Rupert.  They seem to be able to handle the larger size just fine. 

The experiences of the NS, BNSF and CN refute the notion that bigger is less efficient in railroading.  The jurry is still out on the UP.  I don't want to talk about CSX, they still don't know what they do for a living. 

Kent T. Healy may not have been wrong at the time he wrote, but he seems to be out of date.  Of course, that's not his fault.  It's hard to stay up to date when you've been deceased for 20 years.  May he rest in Eternal Peace and never have to worry about a railroad operating ratio again.  God Rest His Soul.

    

"By many measures, the U.S. freight rail system is the safest, most efficient and cost effective in the world." - Federal Railroad Administration, October, 2009. I'm just your average, everyday, uncivilized howling "anti-government" critic of mass government expenditures for "High Speed Rail" in the US. And I'm gosh darn proud of that.
  • Member since
    October 2004
  • 3,190 posts
Posted by MichaelSol on Monday, November 20, 2006 11:40 PM
 bobwilcox wrote:
 marcimmeker wrote:

Bob, I think Michael's response answers the question about the impact of pc's and the internet on productivityWink [;)]

By the way, Michael, thanks for that info.

greetings,

Marc Immeker



Yes it does, his sizeable contribution was made before the arrival of PC and the internet. I think he passed away about 20 years ago.

Well, whatever this means. You just can't throw out something like "computers" or "global warming" and say it explains or does not explain something important without some data.

A McKinsey consulting report in 2001 pointed out that there was a poor correlation between productivity and IT spending.

The report looked at all 60 sectors of the US economy, finding that most of the productivity growth in the U.S. economy after 1995 came from only six sectors: Retail trade, wholesale trade, computer manufacturing, semiconductor manufacturing, securities trading, and telecom services.

Three sectors that spent heavily on computer and internet technology  -- hotels, retail banking, and long-distance data telephony -- had little to show by way of productivity gains.

Railroads have not been a sector that has shown actual productivity benefits as a result of IT investments. If you have a study to the contrary, I would like to see it.

 

  • Member since
    December 2001
  • From: Crozet, VA
  • 1,049 posts
Posted by bobwilcox on Monday, November 20, 2006 9:15 PM
 marcimmeker wrote:

Bob, I think Michael's response answers the question about the impact of pc's and the internet on productivityWink [;)]

By the way, Michael, thanks for that info.

greetings,

Marc Immeker

 



Yes it does, his sizeable contribution was made before the arrival of PC and the internet. I think he passed away about 20 years ago.
Bob
  • Member since
    April 2003
  • 305,205 posts
Posted by Anonymous on Monday, November 20, 2006 6:57 PM

BTW - For those of you who claim you are paying higher electric bills due to energy deregulation (and I mean genuine deregulation which includes the open access caveat, not the partial dereg of Staggers), you might find this interesting.....

http://www.energycentral.com/site/newsletters/ebi.cfm?id=238

.....as it seems that the Texas dereg experiment (which includes OA over transmission lines) has resulted in "significantly lower" electric bills for the average Texas customer. 

Quote of Note:  "A residential customer in Houston, for example, would have saved $1,450 over the last four years while one in Dallas would have saved $800."

Furthermore, there is the innovation factor - " At the same time, the commission says that deregulation has spawned innovative pricing options as well as new green products and services."

So, as we debate whether the electric utility comparison to an OA rail system is apt or not, at least admit that energy dereg (when it's done right as it seems to have been done in Texas) does lower prices for the customers.

Thank you, that's all.

  • Member since
    November 2002
  • From: NL
  • 614 posts
Posted by MStLfan on Monday, November 20, 2006 3:31 PM

Bob, I think Michael's response answers the question about the impact of pc's and the internet on productivityWink [;)]

By the way, Michael, thanks for that info.

greetings,

Marc Immeker

 

For whom the Bell Tolls John Donne From Devotions upon Emergent Occasions (1623), XVII: Nunc Lento Sonitu Dicunt, Morieris - PERCHANCE he for whom this bell tolls may be so ill, as that he knows not it tolls for him; and perchance I may think myself so much better than I am, as that they who are about me, and see my state, may have caused it to toll for me, and I know not that.
  • Member since
    October 2004
  • 3,190 posts
Posted by MichaelSol on Monday, November 20, 2006 3:10 PM
 bobwilcox wrote:
 MichaelSol wrote:

Well, it's not my theory, but rather the results of a study by a well known railroad economist. Kent Healy has probably done more statistical work on post WWII railroads than anyone.



Who is Kent Healy and what has he published?  Does his research consider the impact of PCs and the internet on productivity?

Healy is pretty well known.

"TRUTH about mergers - railroad mergers" Railway Age, November 1998, by Frank N. Wilner.

"...Yale Economics Professor Kent Healy taught a Legion of students two generations ago that economies of scale evaporate when railroads expand to the size they are today.

"As a gut-wrenching validation of that theory, Healy's apostles point to Union Pacific's service hiccup when it absorbed the Chicago and North Western in 1995 and UP's tumble over Niagara Falls following its 1996 acquisition of Southern Pacific. Some even suggest the relative success of Burlington Northern's 1995 merger with the Santa Fe is owed mostly to fleeing Union Pacific customers."

From the Third Quarter 2006 issue of the American Association of Railroad Superintendent's Journal: "Taylor worked for the Nickle Plate Railroad, Union Railroad, Bessemer Lake Erie Railroad as a trainmaster, the Rock Island Railroad as vice president and controller, Amtrak as regional vice president for the Midwest, and TTX as assistant vice president where he retired in 1991. Taylor served on the AARS board of directors for seven years and was treasurer from 1986 to 1991. [Taylor got his start in the] Yale course taught by Kent T. Healy, [which] was famous for churning out several railroad CEOs and high ranking officials. When Taylor took the course, tuition was $450 a semester."

Press Release, April 1996, University of Pennsylvania: A new fund has been set up at the School of Engineering and Applied Science to create a national program to attract student interest in transportation careers.

The Kent T. Healy Fund, Inc., a group of active and retired railroad executives, has set out to "stimulate interest in and knowledge of transportation, with particular reference to railroads, and to encourage young men and women to choose careers in transportation, particularly railroad man-agement and engineering," according to Downing B. Jenks, president of the Fund and former President of Missouri Pacific Railroad. One of the gifts that launches the program is $10,000 from the Kent T. Healy Fund, and the other is $300,000 in the form of a charitable remainder trust from Mr. Jenks, his wife, and his children.

The Kent T. Healy Fund, Inc., was formed in 1985 by alumni of the late Professor Kent T. Healy of Yale University, to honor their professor and mentor and to continue his work in preparing students for careers in transportation. "Professor Healy's graduates have had a major impact on the industry and have included 30 presidents and vice presidents of railroads and railroad suppliers,"said Dean Gregory Farrington of SEAS in acknowledging the gift.

Works:

Electrification of Steam Railroads, 1929. by Kent T. Healy

Healy, Kent T. “Development of Transportation in Southern New England.” Annual Report of the Connecticut Society of Civil Engineers (1934):95-12

Cases on Railroad Economics: Supplemented by selected statistics (1938)
by Kent T. Healy 


Kent T. Healy, The Economics of Transportation in America: Development,
Organization, Functioning and Regulation
(New York, 1940).

The Effects of Scale in the Railroad Industry
,
Kent T. Healy (New Haven, Connecticut, Yale University Press, 1961).

Some Major Aspects of Urban Transportation Policy Formation, By Kent Healy (1963)


Performance of the U. S. Railroads since World War II: A Quarter Century of Private Operation by Kent T. Healy, Review author[s]: Albro Martin, Business History Review, Vol. 61, No. 1 (Spring, 1987), pp. 160-162,. Martin's description of Healy's background is illuminating:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0007-6805(198721)61%3A1%3C160%3APOTUSR%3E2.0.CO%3B2-W

Join our Community!

Our community is FREE to join. To participate you must either login or register for an account.

Search the Community

Newsletter Sign-Up

By signing up you may also receive occasional reader surveys and special offers from Trains magazine.Please view our privacy policy