QUOTE: Originally posted by rob_l Mark said: "One place where the philosophy of Kenefick stands out is motive power: Rather than the peculiar infatuation with big, inflexible, high-tonnage machines of the 1960s, namely the double-diesels and turbines, the Kenefick era zeroed in on two standardized locomotives, the SD40-2 for all types of main-line service (and its GE equivalent, the C30-7), and the GP38-2 for branch line and secondary service. Standardization is the hallmark of a railroad manager who seeks efficiency of the total operation, not just pieces of it that catch his fancy or speak to his background." The standardization of UP motive power is really the doing of Frank Accord, who Kenefick brought over from NYC to succeed D S Neuhart as UP Chief Mechanical Officer. Accord had complete autonomy to decide what to do about motive power. I think his decisions had little or nothing to do with the total operation, they really had to do with cutting motive power maintenance costs. The last straw was the U50C disaster (VPO Bill Fox called it "the biggest goof we ever made"), after that there was this gigantic swing in the opposite direction to make UP motive power as dull and as conservative as possible. And in this Accord succeeded very well. Accord did have to give in from pressures in the Traffic and Transportation Depts. for high-speed service, and so he was forced to re-gear a block of SD40-2s with passenger gearing (the so-called Fast Forties). But by and large he left his mark by making the UP motive power roster about as unimaginative and uninspired as anyone could conceive. Although it's possible, I doubt Kenefick provided significant direction about striving for motive power cost savings by turning the UP into an SD40-2 railroad. To the contrary, I think he was quite enamored with being able to run a lot faster than the competition using the Centennials, with the PR prestige from having bigger, faster power than anybody else and with running a better carload railroad service than anybody else. This was the UP legacy he strived to uphold. He really was an Old School guy in that respect, perhaps even besting Al Perlman as the best of the old-era, quality-service managers. So I think it is very appropriate that they are planning a Kenefick Park on top of the hill in Omaha overlooking the MIssouri with a Centennial and a Big Boy stuffed and mounted therein. That's the kind of railroading where his heart was. Best regards, Rob L.
QUOTE: Originally posted by M.W. Hemphill Greyhounds: Your analysis of the effects of regulation on the Rio Grande and Union Pacific is unlikely to inspire disagreement from any reasonable person I have met. However, depending on who I am, I can think of broad benefits of economic regulation of transportation. While arguments can be waged that it cost the U.S. economy this or that, that's not relevant to the person who Does Not Care what happens to the U.S. economy. Specifically, regulation was hugely beneficial for small shippers and anyone interested in transportation to or from a small town or to a location off the main routes of commerce. It gave the one-car-a week coal mine the same rate as a thousand-car-a-day coal mine. If I am the small coal mine I like that a great deal, because it keeps me in business. If I want to live in a country that allows small businessmen to get into business, and hinders the large businessman's power, I want regulation of the market. If I want to live in a country that gives the consumer the lowest possible price, I want deregulation of the market. An assertion today that regulation would be good, or bad, as a summary judgement, based on today's value system, can be made. If it's a consistent and defensible argument, it will probably stick. Projected backward, it's an ahistorical assertion unless it considers the value system of the past. Slavery, for instance, was a good deal for the slaveowner. Bad for the slaves and for later generations, but apparently that didn't concern the slaveowners very much. Ahistorical assertions also diverts attention from the larger question: why it is that a majority of Americans in the past found economic regulation desirable, and why it is that a majority of Americans find it undesirable now. After all, we did it: railroad regulation was not imposed by aliens or evil overlords, but by Americans. So why did America change? What it was that led Americans to believe railroad regulation was a good idea in the late 1800s, and about a century later to conclude it was a bad idea? I submit that regulation and deregulation both were logical outcomes of substantial reassessments of what it was people wanted out of their lives. Of the first change, most historians consider it a revolt against modernity and an emphasis that America should remain a nation of individuals of roughly equal economic power, along with a strong fear of classism, monarchies, immigrants, certain religions, and ironically, a fear of distant control. Of the second change, most historians consider it a revolt against limits on individual expression and self-realization, namely, limits on the personal expression called "I want to get really rich and accumulate cool toys." Ironically, it also includes a strong fear of distant control. The irony of the past is that to achieve regulation, control of the market had to be vested in distant Washington, with a dubious oversight called the popular vote, and the irony of the present is that to achieve individual wealth, control has to be vested in distant boards of directors, with a dubious oversight called the annual election of the board of directors. I find deeply incisive what BNSF VP Stevan Bobb said to me two years ago to explain grain rates: "We believe in equal opportunities, not equal outcomes." That is, everyone has the freedom to invest in any piece of land they want and reap all the reward the market will allow, but the railroad (and by extension the government) has no obligation to assure everyone gets the same reward regardless of their decisions. Those who invest in badly located farms get high rates, and those who invest in well located farms get low rates. The economic rent of the land will reflect location.
Our community is FREE to join. To participate you must either login or register for an account.